But
the good news is that at last the key issues are beginning
to be addressed. There are three central issues in power
sector - power purchase agreements and fuel policies; distribution
management; and agricultural power. Let us focus on agricultural
power.
The
oft-repeated goal in agriculture is to make sure that the
tariff is at least 50% of cost of supply, and in any case
should be not less than 50 paise per KWH. But such an approach
has three fallacies. First, cost of supply at current level
of distribution losses and thefts is unsustainable, and
the burden of corruption and inefficiency cannot be transferred
to consumers. In any case agricultural consumption is from
base-load stations during off-peak hours. Second, agricultural
economy itself is going through turbulent times. Any effort
to exorbitantly increase power tariffs for farmers dependant
on lift irrigation is bound to lead to severe political
backlash. No party can afford that. Third, the real issue
in distribution is energy balancing and reducing losses.
Emphasis on tariffs alone will not do.
Given
these factors, we should evolve an effective, practical
and sustainable approach to agricultural power. Mere tariff
increase to close the gap between cost of supply and revenue
realization will not work. What then is the way out?
Let
us look at the facts. Out of the power sector losses of
nearly Rs 40,000 crores, agricultural subsidies account
for about Rs 6,000 crore. But the real damage is on account
of non-metering of agricultural power in many states. Tamil
Nadu, AP, Karnataka, MP, UP, Bihar, Punjab and several other
states do not meter agricultural power. They either supply
power at a slab rate based on connected load (a fixed amount
per annum per connected HP), or provide power free as in
Tamil Nadu, and in Punjab until now. Non-metering has three
serious consequences. First, there is no energy balancing,
and nobody knows what the T & D losses are. In AP for
instance, all that we know is that only about 43% of the
power which goes into the grid is metered and billed. The
balance 57% is either agricultural consumption, or technical
losses in T & D, or thefts. We have neither precise
idea of how much power is lost and in what manner, nor are
we in a position to localize the problem. Localization is
the key to reducing losses and thefts. Second, the farmer
has no incentive to save electricity, as his tariff is not
based on consumption. It is always tempting to keep the
motor on as long as power supply is available. Higher capacity,
low-efficiency motors are installed since the slab rate
is low. A lot of energy is wasted, causing losses to power
sector and damaging the environment. Third, in low rainfall
zones water table is fast-depleting, causing long-term damage
to agriculture.
The
answer therefore is clear. Our first priority should be
to meter every single agricultural consumer, and have a
low, graded tariff based on consumption. Tariff should increase
with consumption to discourage waste. The policy should
be aimed at conservation of ground water, and water-intensive
crops should be prohibited under lift irrigation. Finally,
there should be an incentive for metering. For instance,
under each agricultural feeder, if 80% of farmers accept
metering, better quality of power (longer hours, more convenient
time etc) can be guaranteed. Agricultural power policy,
in the first instance, should be revenue-neutral for a reasonable
period (say, five years), and should aim at energy conservation,
metering, and graded tariff. Only then can we save power,
balance energy, localize thefts and losses and improve distribution.
Power saved, when sold to industrial and commercial sectors,
will yield much more revenue than higher agricultural tariffs.
High tariffs in agriculture will simply not work. The impossible
best, as they say, is the enemy of the possible good.
***