But
the remark of Chief Election Commissioner Lyngdoh that simultaneous
polls cannot be held because of security concerns is a severe
indictment of our democratic process. That we have come
to a stage over the past two decades when vast armies of
security personnel have to be moved from place to place
at enormous expense and effort in order to maintain peace
and order during polling in several states is a testimony
to the distortions that crept into our system. The issue
is not whether we can spare over a million policemen to
conduct elections. Can democracy be meaningful if habitual
use of force, terror, deceit and inducement determines the
outcome of elections?
Our
democracy is alive and kicking. There is genuine political
competition; ruling parties and powerful candidates often
lose the elections; there is constant change of players
with half the incumbents being unseated in every election;
the verdict broadly refects public opinion; and there is
constant political churning. But a closer look at our electoral
scene reveals disturbing trends of violence, criminalization,
money power and deceit. Clearly the past two decades have
witnessed heightened political contention and dramatic rise
in violence and illegitimate money power in elections. And
yet our democracy is resilient. A system of compensatory
errors ensures that the malpractices of a candidate are
neutralised by his rival! Added to that, the strength of
Election Commission, neutrality of public officials, and
a tradition of governments not interfering in electoral
process have ensured some sanity in our politics.
But
the fact is politics has become big business. Often individuals
and families with abnormal money power, acquired through
political patronage or corruption, are unassailable in the
electoral arena. In many constituencies these modern fiefdoms
hold sway with money power, political contacts, caste mobilization
and criminal links. All major parties are forced to depend
on such individuals to enhance their chance of success in
the first-past-the-post-system. Once such persons are elected,
they seek multiple returns on investment through influence
peddling, state patronage and control over public purse.
Parliamentary debate, rational public discourse and sensible
policies are rendered largely irrelevant.
While
simultaneous election at all levels may not be feasible
within Westminster model, we can no longer ignore certain
serious questions plaguing our polity. We have to address
these important issues on the basis of what is said; not
deflect them on grounds of who said it. We need to recognize
the genuine problems of governance, and evolve mechanisms
which do not allow public good to be held hostage to the
short-term quest for power and patronage. We need to make
power work for people, and not for private aggrandizement.
What,
then, needs to be done? First, it is possible to fill casual
vacancies to legislative office through election by local
government representatives instead of by-elections. Simple
changes can accomplish this, and avoid the need for expensive
by-elections which distract attention from governance
Second,
the real problem of governance is in states. Honesty and
survival in power are increasingly incompatible in our parliamentary
executive model. The executive is captive in the hands of
legislators whose primary concern is with patronage and
spoils of office. Today, government's accountability to
legislature is but a myth. A government with a captive majority
is unassailable, and there is an unholy alliance between
the executive and legislature. We need clear separation
of powers and direct election of the head of government.
Once it is certain that power cannot be divorced from people's
mandate, the nature of government will undergo a transformation.
The legislature will be elected directly, and will control
the budget, law-making and key appointments, and will exercise
oversight functions. A directly elected executive in states
can always be kept under check by the union government and
constitutional functionaries. Such separation of powers
at the union level is both unnecessary and undesirable.
Fears of majoritarian domination and genuine concerns about
authoritarian tendencies of a directly elected head of state
at national level who is also the supreme commander of armed
forces cannot be dismissed lightly. The quasi-authoritarian
emergency between 1975 and 77 taught us never to underestimate
the authoritarian impulses of the union executive.
Third,
the union executive can be made more stable by introducing
the practice of constructive no confidence motion, whereby
a government can be voted out only if an alternative is
in place. Article 67 of the German Basic Law can be the
model we can adopt. This does not guarantee fixed term of
the House, since a government without majority support cannot
get bills passed or budget approved. However, it will curb
impulsive no-confidence motions.
Finally,
we need to break the stranglehold of semi-feudal fiefdoms
on our polity. Good and honorable candidates must have realistic
chances of success at the polls. Scattered minorities must
get fair representation. For this, we need to adopt a model
of mixed proportional representation whereby a party will
gain legislative presence in proportion to its vote. In
order to prevent fragmentation of our polity, a reasonable
threshold, say 10% vote in a major state, should be imposed
for gaining representation. Internal party democracy, and
nomination of candidates through secret ballot are the essential
pre-requites of a proportional system of election.
Given
foresight and good will, these reforms are well within our
reach. The crisis of governance which has become the hall
mark of our polity can be effectively addressed only if
we embark on these sensible reforms quickly. Short term,
knee-jerk responses will only camouflage the crisis, and
further retard our democratic evolution and economic growth.
***